The perverse economics of habitat conversion

Deforestation in Sumatra: what is the value of intact forest versus cleared land? © Marco Lambertini/BirdLife

The conversion of natural habitats makes no economic sense once currently unmarketed ecological services are taken into account. On average, c.50% of the total economic value of natural habitat is lost following its wholesale conversion to a more intense human use.


Total economic value of relatively intact natural habitat compared to an alternative land use, for five case-studies across four biomes
NPV = Net Present Value, in year-2000 US$ per hectare, Balmford et al. (2002)

There have been few studies of the economics of converting relatively intact habitats to human uses such as crop cultivation, aquaculture or plantation forestry. Even fewer have attempted to take into account the multiple and interdependent nature of the goods and services provided by ecosystems. A recent literature survey found only five such case-studies, covering only four biomes (Turner et al. 2002, Balmford et al. 2002; see figure).

In four out of the five case-studies, habitat conversion made economic sense to the convertors, in terms of the short-term private benefits accruing to them—especially when subsidies were taken into account (Balmford et al. 2002). However, even when some of the private benefits are accrued by the local population (which is often not the case), they frequently fail to filter down to subsistence users (the poorest segment of society), thereby increasing poverty and inequality (Turner et al. 2002).

In all five cases, however, once the wider, unmarketed costs to society had been accounted for, in terms of the loss of ecosystem services, the public costs of habitat conversion were found to outweigh the private benefits by c.50% on average (see figure; Balmford et al. 2002). Habitat conversion does not make sense from the perspective of global sustainability. Indeed, the economic benefits of conserving the world’s remaining natural habitat appear to exceed the costs by at least 100 to 12.

Such case-studies highlight some of the reasons why drastic conversion and degradation of the Earth’s remaining natural habitats have continued largely unabated since the Earth Summit in 1992, and why many countries are not on track to meet the United Nations’ goals for human development and poverty eradication by 2015 (Balmford et al. 2002, UNDP 2001).


Related Case Studies in other sections

References

Balmford A., Bruner, A., Cooper P., Costanza R., Farber, S., Green, R. E., Jenkins, M., Jefferiss, P., Jessamy, V., Madden, J., Munro, K., Myers, N., Naeem, S., Paavola, J., Rayment, M., Rosendo, S., Roughgarden, J., Trumper, K. and Kerry Turner, R. (2002) Economic reasons for conserving wild nature. Science 297: 950–953.
 
Turner, K., Paavola, J., Cooper, P., Farber, S., Jessamy, V. and Georgiou, S. (2002) Valuing nature: lessons learned and future research directions. Norwich, UK: Centre for Social and Economic Research on the Global Environment.
 
UNDP (2001) Human development report 2001. New York: United Nations Development Programme.

Compiled: 2004    Copyright: 2004   

Recommended Citation:
BirdLife International (2004) The perverse economics of habitat conversion. Downloaded from https://datazone.birdlife.org/sowb/casestudy/the-perverse-economics-of-habitat-conversion on 25/11/2024